Why is the ‘Flash Boys’ Exchange Still Controversial?

(Bloomberg View) — If you are interested in market structure and high-frequency trading,you might want to go have a look at the comments thatthe Securities and Exchange Commission has received on IEX’s application to become a public stock exchange. Manyof them provide illuminating discussions of contested questions of market structure. Many, though, don’t. Instead, they providea sort of illuminating meta-discussion of market structure; they give you a sense of what we talk about when we talk about market structure. It’s not market structure! It’s this:

What could possibly be the objection to competition?That is all it is. IEX is a place of business that willoffer me, the investor, a choice.

Why is Ameritrade paid for their quote stream? We know the answer.

The IEX will provide transparency for all.

Or this:

IEX is a force for good in the finance industry, please support it and do not try to bar it from operating. Investors have been fleeced for too long throughdark poolsand payment for order flow.

thanks

(Keep in mind that IEX, right now, is adarkpool.)My favorite might be this one:

Thanks for reading my comments. I would not want to repeat what has been said so accurately by Mr. Hunsader (founder of nanex llc), Joe Saluzzi of Themis trading, and Michael Lewis despite being a well know novelist have been unquestionably and verifiably correct on the damage high frequency trading. High- frequency trading or high-frequency traders as defined under the context that they have a significant speed advantage and have a direct feed to the exchanges while all the other consolidated feeds and subscribers of those consolidated feeds actually fall behind. We not only we not only urge you but also bestow upon you the duty to do The right thing of approving an exchange that will actually help investors and the US economy as a whole by leveling the playing field. Not so surprisingly citadel and other prominent HFT have commented up to multiple times against allowing IEX to be an exchange. Now their choice being against IEX is also their right, but they’re right should not deter the average investors from actually getting a good fill, and freedom from being prayed upon by predatory high-frequency trading practices.

Please do think about the investors who are

It ends there. Perhaps it is a sort of concrete poetry meant to suggest that investors are getting front-run so cruelly that they can’t even finish their sentences?

Anyway, you get the idea. A lot of people really like IEX! Even if they don’t, strictly speaking, know what it is! It has really good marketing! There is a book — my Bloomberg View colleague Michael Lewis’s “Flash Boys,” which is nota novel — and the IEX people are charming, and their pitch is that they want to make the worldfairer for investors.So investors who feel like the world isn’tfair for them — because of Ameritrade ordark poolsor payment for order flow or direct feeds or whatever else — identify emotionally with IEX. Surely the SEC should approve their application to be an exchange, because then things will be fairer. But it hasn’t yet, and IEX just gave the SEC another three months to think about it.Here isGretchen Morgenson:

Scores of investors, in a fistful of comments, have told the Securities and Exchange Commission that they want to be able to trade stocks on a more level playing field. So why hasnt the commission, known as theInvestor Advocate, given the green light to an operation that would enable it?

Of course, if the SEC were judging IEX’s application strictly on its marketing pitch,on its emotional resonance, it would approve the application in a heartbeat. The SEC commissioners would travel to New York to carry IEX’s co-founder Brad Katsuyama around ontheir shoulders, shouting “huzzah.”

But the poor SEC actually has to read all the comment letters and think, not about whether Fairness Is Good, but about whether IEX’s application to be an exchange is legal and will improve markets. And it turns out that, despite the glowing comments above, some people do have objections to IEX’s application.Morgenson insinuates that “established exchanges aren’t keen on the IEX application” because it represents unwanted competition for them,but you can actually go read their comments, and IEX’s responses. And if you do, a real and interesting controversy emerges.

The basic pitchof IEX is that big institutional investors can use it to trade stocks safely, without being preyed upon by high-frequency traders. IEX does some things to protect this safety — itdoesn’t use maker/taker pricing, doesn’t offer faster access to high-frequency traders, etc. — but the most famous, and the one that is at issue in its application, is IEX’s “POP,” or “speed bump,” or “magic shoebox.” This is a coil of wires in a box that delays every trader’s communications with IEX by 350 microseconds. If you submit an order to IEX, IEX will wait 350 microseconds to post or execute it, and when IEX executes a trade, it will wait 350 microseconds to tell the parties that their trade executed.

It’s important to realize that slowing everyone down by 350 microseconds can’t possibly help anyone.As Hudson River Trading said in its comment letter: “Similar to a 100-meter sprint, if you simply add 350 microseconds to each participants time, neither the order in which they finish nor their time differentials will change.”So for normal market and limit orders on IEX — in its current incarnation as adarkpool, or its possible future incarnation as an exchange — thedelay is pretty much an irrelevancy. If there is stock available for $10.00 on IEX, and Big Nice Institution wants to buy it, and Evil HFT wants to buy it, then whichever submits its order to IEX first will end up buying it. They’ll both be delayed by 350 microseconds, but that doesn’t change the result.And since Evil HFT is faster, it will beat Big Nice Institution to the shares.

So how can the magic shoeboxever help? The trick is that some actions on IEX arenotsubject to the 350-microsecond delay. The idea is that sometimes IEX will, on behalf of its institutional-investor customers, cut ahead of the line, because the line is full of predatory high-frequency traders. That’s the wholecontroversy. IEX thinks that the high-frequency traders are unfair and predatory, and so it is protecting its customers by cutting those HFTs out of the loop in a few cases where otherwise the HFTs might do predatory things. The high-frequency traders, on the other hand, think that they’re not especially predatory, and that letting anyone cut ahead of them in line is unfair. The question for the SEC is, roughly speaking, does fairness require being fair to high-frequency traders (who lots of people think are themselvesunfair)?

If you stop reading now — and you probably should! — you will have a decent sense of the philosophical issues at issue in IEX’s exchange application, which are not quite Fairness vs. Unfairness but rather What Does Fairness Even Mean? For the rest of you, let’s talk in more detail about the market-structure issues, though I warn you that things are about to get significantly more market structure-y in here.

Sotwo specific actions at IEX are not subject to the 350- microsecond magic shoebox delay. The first is updating ofpegged orders. The idea of a pegged order is that Big Nice Institution submits a hidden order to buy stock at the midpoint of the national best bid and offer. So if stock is trading at $10.00 bid, $10.01 offered, Big Nice Institution will submit a pegged order to IEX to buy at the midpoint ($10.005). If someone comes to IEX with a market sell order (i.e., willing to sell at $10.00), Big Nice Institution will buyits shares at $10.005, saving itself half the spread versus if it had used a market order itself. This order type exists on other exchanges too, and it ispopular ondark pools, which are to some extent built around the intuition thatbig nice institutions should be able to trade with each other secretly at the midpoint between the bid and the offer.

But there is a problem with pegged orders. Let’s say that the best bid for a stock is $10.00 for 500 shares on the New York Stock Exchange (and there are no other $10.00 bids anywhere), and a tradergoes to NYSE and tries to sell 1,000 sharesat $10.00. That trader takes out all the $10.00 bids, leaving the national best bid at $9.99; it also leaves a 500- share offer on the NYSE book, improving the national best offer to $10.00. Now the midpoint is $9.995.But it takes a bit of time forotherexchanges,andotherdark pools, to figure this out:NYSE’s execution isn’t communicated to them instantaneously.In fact, generally speaking, electronic traders can learn about this price change before other exchanges anddark poolsdo, because they often have faster access to execution information, and more generally because their technology tends to be speedier. So if Evil HFTknows that the national best bid and offer are $9.99 at $10.00, and it knows that, for the tiniest fraction of a second, itcan go to IEX and sell at $10.005 — because IEXhasn’t updated its midpoint peg orders yet — then that is (a tiny bit of) free money for Evil HFT.

So IEX’s pegged-order logic cuts ahead of its magic shoebox to update those pegged orders. In the previous example, Big Nice Institution has a midpoint peg order to buy at $10.005, based on a $10.00 / $10.01 national best bid and offer. Then the national best bid and offer change to $9.99 / $10.00. Evil HFT sees this and rushes to sell all the stock it can at $10.005 against pegged buy orders on other exchanges anddark pools. But it is stymied at IEX: Its sell order is delayed by 350 microseconds, while IEX itself skips the magic shoebox and immediately updates its pegged orders to reflect the new national best bid and offer. So Big Nice Institution can’t be picked off by Evil HFT on its pegged order.

IEX also cuts ahead of its magic shoebox forroutable orders. The idea of a routable order is, let’s say that there are 10,000 shares of stock for sale at $10.01, of which 2,000 are available on IEX and 8,000 are available elsewhere. Big Nice Institution sends an order to IEX to buy 10,000 shares, and lets IEX route it: IEX is in charge of getting, not just the shares available on its own platform, but as many shares as it can get. So IEX executes 2,000 shares on its own exchange.It turns out, though, that the seller of those 2,000 shares was Evil HFT. Not only that, but Evil HFT is the one offering those 8,000 shares of stock at $10.01 elsewhere. IEXtells Big Nice Institution and Evil HFT that their trade for 2,000 shares has executed. “Aha!” thinks Evil HFT, “I know there’s a big buyer of stock, since I just sold 2,000 shares all at once. I’ll move up all my prices elsewhere, to make that big buyer pay more for the stock.” And so Evil HFT cancels all of its $10.01 offers on other exchanges, and replaces them withoffers at $10.02. And since Evil HFT is faster than IEX’s router, it can cancel and re-submit those orders before IEX’s router even gets to the other exchanges with Big Nice Institution’s order. And so now Big Nice Institution can only get 2,000 shares at the posted price of $10.01; the other 8,000 shares come at $10.02 or worse.

Or that’s how it would work, except that IEX lets its router cut the line here too. So when it executes those 2,000 shares, the magic shoebox delays its notification to Evil HFT (and Big Nice Institution). But IEX’s own router gets the order to buy 8,000 more shares immediately, and has a 350-microsecond head start on Evil HFT when it runs ahead to the other exchanges. So it can beat Evil HFT there, and buy stock at $10.01 before Evil HFT can cancel and re-submit its orders. As IEX puts it, the idea is “to prevent ‘information leakage’ or ‘liquidity fade’ when IEXS routes to other markets.”

I have tried, in the previous five paragraphs, to describe IEX’s proposal in terms that are pretty favorable to it.Sure I used the phrase “cut the line,” which has some negative connotations, and is perhaps unfair; it is not a priori obvious that IEX’s pegged orders or routable ordersshouldhave to go through the magic shoebox again. (Those orders, after all, went through the magic shoebox once when they first came to IEX, so why should they have to go through again to update the peg or to route away?)In any case, even if IEX is cutting the line, it is only doing so to help out big nice institutions at the expense of evil high-frequency traders.

But there are objections. One objection is just that it is always unfair for public stock exchanges to delay quotes. A public stock exchange’s quotes are “protected,” meaning that if IEX has the best price then brokers have to trade with it before going elsewhere. But if IEX’s quotations are always intentionally 350 microseconds out of date, then that will mess up market transparency and price discovery, because you will be forced to trade with IEX quotes even if you don’t know that they’re real. This objection has a certain power. For one thing, the SEC’s rules seem to say that a protected quotation can’t have intentional delays; as Citadel said inits second comment letter, “IEX simply cannot hide from the letter of the law.” For another thing, this objection is obviously right forsomelength of delay: Of coursebrokers shouldn’t be forced to send orders to an exchange whose quotations are 20minutes out of date.But in the actual world, with a 350 microsecond delay, this objection is mostlysilly; we have talked about it before, and let’s not talk about it again, except maybe in a footnote.

There are more interestingobjections, though.Aminor but intriguing one has to do with the interaction of IEX routable orders and pegged orders onotherexchanges.It goes like this. Let’s say the national best bid and offer are $10.00 / $10.01, the $10.00 bids are all at IEX, and Other FriendlyInstitution has a midpoint pegged buy order on the New York Stock Exchange. Big NiceInstitution sends a routable sell order to IEX, taking out all of the $10.00 bids. Now the national best bid and offer are $9.99 / $10.01, making the midpoint $10.00. But IEX’s router sends Big NiceInstitution’s order to NYSE before NYSE knows to update the price, so that order executes at $10.005 (the stale midpoint) instead of $10.00 (the current midpoint). IEX has helped Big Nice Institution pick off Other Friendly Institution’s midpoint peg order on NYSE. Big NiceInstitution, abetted by IEX, is doing exactly what Evil HFT was doing back in the first example about pegged orders: It’s trading against pegged orders on other exchanges at stale prices.

That example is cribbed from a comment letter by BATS, a competing exchange, which adds:

The above example reflects the same type of latency arbitrage IEX complains about. As currently architected, in addition to discriminating against other broker-dealers that must wait to receive an execution message through the POP before routing to other trading venues, IEX is disadvantaging the same orders on other venues that it seeks to protect on IEX.

That is a bit of anexaggeration. If IEX didn’t have the magic shoebox, its router and the high-frequency traders and NYSE and Other FriendlyInstitution would all be in a race to get to NYSE’s pegged orders first, and probably NYSE and Other FriendlyInstitution wouldn’t win, so the result would be about the same: Other FriendlyInstitution’s pegged order would still be picked off. So this is not a problem that is unique to IEX. And I don’t really know how IEX couldfix this; just requiring IEX’s router to go through the shoebox probably wouldn’t work. Nor do I think that this is likely to be a huge or frequent problem.

Still it isawkwardthat IEX might find itself in the position of using latency arbitrage to pick off passive institutional investors at other exchanges. Not onlybecause that is a little gross, and not only because that’s what the magic shoebox is designed to prevent on IEX, but alsobecause it raises the specter of other exchanges introducing their own delays to protect themselves against IEX. The worrying prospect is that anIEX as an exchangemight increasemarket complexity, rather than decreasing it, as high-frequency traders and other exchanges adopt new rules and new advantages to counteract the advantages that IEX gives its own router.

Another objection — in some waysthe main objection — is just, like, go read the two paragraphsabout routable orders again, except take out the word “Evil” in the name “Evil HFT.” Because if you are a high-frequency trader, you don’t think that updating your orders to reflect trading activity is evil, or “predatory,” or “phantom liquidity,” or whatever other bad thing IEX thinks it is. You think that it is traditional market-making and prudent risk management. We’ve talked before about why high- frequency traders cancel so many orders. One viewis that they are just spoofing and manipulating and front-running and so forth, offering phantom liquidity to trick institutions into trading with them. But another, quitestandard and orthodox view is that they are basically functioning as market makers, and the way you make markets is by responding to trading information. So if you sell 2,000 shares at $10.01, then you should raise your prices so that you sell the next 2,000 shares at $10.02, and you should try to do that as quickly as possible so you don’t sell more shares at $10.01, because $10.01 is now the “wrong” price. If you keep selling shares at $10.01, you are selling them too cheaply.

In other words, the objection goes, IEX uses the magic shoebox (and its router’s ability to skip the shoebox) to do “latency arbitrage” and trade with stale quotes on other exchanges before traders on those exchanges can update their quotes, just like it accuses high-frequency traders of doing to its own investors. And, the objection goes, if it’s unfair for high-frequency traders to do this to IEX’s customers, then it’s just as unfair for IEX’s customers to do it to high-frequency traders.

This is acore conflict in market structure. Big institutional investors — many of whom back IEX’s application – – want to be able to buy lots of shares without moving the price. (They want to “pick off” electronictraders,the electronic traderswould say.) Electronic market makers want to be able to change their prices in response to new information, where “new information” means in particular “big institutions buying lots of shares.” (They want to “front run” the institutions, the institutions would say.)People get absolutely blue in the face about the moral dimensions of this conflict, but of course there are none.Investment managers want what’s better for them, and electronic traders want what’s better for them, and morality has nothing to do with it.

Economicshas something to do with it, althoughthe economics are hotly disputed and not as simple as evil high- frequency traders front-running real investors and stealing money from them. By being able to update their prices quickly, electronic traders might be able tooffer tighter markets– making it cheaper to trade small amounts of stock — and tomake prices more accurate and efficient.You might disagree, and think that the benefits they offer are illusory or at least small relative to their disadvantages. But the SEC seems to think that the current market structure, with markets largely made by electronic traders, is mostly good.

Of course, the SEC can think that, and IEX can think the opposite; there is room for diverse viewpoints in market structure. Like that first commenter said, the point of IEX is to offer investors a choice. IEX, as adarkpool, has arguably set itself up to favor long-term institutional investors at the expense of high-frequency traders.The concern about its application to be an exchange is, while it is fine foradarkpooltodo that, anexchangeisn’t supposed tofavor either side. A public exchange has certain regulatory advantages — mainly, that brokers are sometimes required to routeto it — and so has to be equallyopen to institutions and brokers and electronic traders and anyone else who wants to trade.

One responseto that objection would be that most exchanges right now are set up to favor high-frequency traders over “real” investors, and that IEX is just restoring a bit of balance. That seems to be mostly IEX’s view, and has an obvious appeal: If every other exchange offers high-frequency traders faster access to its data, why shouldn’t IEX be allowed to offer them, in effect,sloweraccess? Why shouldn’t it be allowed to briefly hide information to prevent “leakage” or “latency arbitrage” or other stuff that it (and its customers) thinks is harmful to real investors? Another response would bethat favoring “real,” long-term investors over high-frequency traders is good, because high-frequency traders are parasites, and so IEX’s efforts to protect institutional investors ought to be allowed even if they do look a bit unfair to electronictraders. This is obviously a popular view, judging by the comment letters, but I am not sure that it’s theSEC’sview.

I suspect that the SEC is not itself sure what its view is, which might be why it needs the extra three months. This stuff is complicated on a nitty market-structure level: What unintended consequences and weird arbitrages might come from allowing IEX’s application? But it is also complicated on a broader philosophical level: What does it mean for an exchange, or a market structure, to be fair? And how fair, and to whom, does an exchange have to be to get the SEC’s blessing?

This column does not necessarily reflect the opinion of the editorial board or Bloomberg LP and its owners.

But there are so many more. Like: I am writing to you regarding support of “IEX” We have a life boat in IEX in the rough seas filled with sharks.(“High Volume Traders”) I urge you to afford the protection of long term investors over short term professional intermediaries. This is why I personally feel its good for the SEC to approve IEXs application to become an Exchange with a protected quotation Why you think you may use the IEX router to eliminate the possibility of having your orders impacted by certain types of speed-enabled trading strategies (aka latency arbitrage) I urge you with all of possible speed and with us in mind whom have been victims of by stealing our money with the disadvantages in current place with today’s exchanges. Or this particularly wonderful one: Dear SEC, I am a future stock investor, currently in the 8th grade at Aberdeen Middle School in Wetlawn Oregon. I whole heartily approve of the IEX plan to slow down trading. Things move too fast in this world and we need to slow it down in every way we can. Take my school for instance. When we stand in line to pay for our lunch, we have two cashiers to pick from. There is Mr. Fields, who was recently fired from a data entry job. I heard he made some creepy comments to one of his female co-workers. But that isn’t important. Mr. Fields can work that cash register like nobodies business. Even when twice as long, most kids will get in Mr. Fields line. Me, on the other hand. I prefer to get in Josephine’s line. She used to work at the DMV before failing a drug test. I always get in her line. Sure, it takes me much longer, but she will always give me a compliment and ask me about my day. In conclusion, IEX should be rewarded for slowing everything down and moving things backward. Cause backwards is awesome Thank you for your time. What are the odds that was written by a legit eighth grader, as opposed to a high-frequency trader having a laugh? Lewisdoes seem to havewriten a comment letter, though, as did Eric Scott Hunsader of Nanex, LLC, andSal Arnuk and Joe Saluzzi of Themis Trading LLC. The letter from “Stephen Colbert” is of perhaps questionable provenance. Here I guess is where I list them. The most interesting comments with market-structure details are probably: There are also a lot of supportive letters from other investment firms praising IEX’s fee structure, transparency, etc., but not addressing the market-structure controversies thatare actually at issue in the application. It’s worth emphasizing, though, that those letters are real enough: A lot of big investors (Capital Group, Southeastern Asset Management, Oppenheimer Funds, etc. ) really like IEX, and really want its application approved, regardless of what you think about the narrow market- structure issues discussed in the text.

You might, of course, find it a bit hypocritical that high- frequency traders, and rival exchanges, are criticizing IEX for this, since a lot of market structure at other exchanges is basically about giving high-frequency traders advantages over other exchanges. IEX surethinks that: We believe that NYSEs professed concern about IEXs complex order types is ironic; the Discretionary Peg order type, like the POP, represents a specific design and response by our market to address the market complexity NYSE and other exchanges have created by introducing multiple markets, order types, and technology products that cater to high speed trading strategies. To that point, in assessing the overall complexity that exchanges add to market structure, it is important to consider not just order types, but also the byzantine menu of proprietary networking and connectivity options of varying latency and capacity (including but not limited to 1GB, 1GB Ultra, 10GB, 10GB Ultra, 10GB LX, 40GB, microwave, fiber optic, unicast, multicast, FPGA, ASCII, binary, dedicated servers), and the mounting variety of market data products offered by the existing exchanges including those operated by NYSE and Nasdaq. These products are marketed, based on their latency reducing performance, as a preferred and even necessary alternative to slower products and they are sold at premiums 5-10 times the cost of slower products. Or similarly if there was a pegged order on the other side, etc. IEX’s pegged orders are a bit more complicated than this, but not in ways that matter. See Rule 11.190(a)(3) here. All examples here are a bit stylized. The main substantive reasons it’s silly are: As for Citadel’s argument that the “letter of the law” forbids the delay,strictly speaking thelaw only requires that an exchange “immediately and automatically” respond to incoming orders. (See the discussion inthis post.) Is 350 microseconds “immediate” enough? I don’t know; it’s tempting to say that, if it’s faster than other exchanges, that’s immediate enough. The adopting release for Regulation NMS says that “the term ‘immediate’ precludes any coding of automated systems or other type of intentional device that would delay the action taken with respect to a quotation,” which is bad, but (1) that’s not the law, just the adopting release and (2) again, other exchanges coil wires, so it’s not clear why IEX’s coiling wouldn’t be allowed. Incidentally, BATS’scommentlettersare supportive of the idea of allowing a speed bump, but ask the SEC to make some rules clarifying how long a speed bump is acceptable. IEX for some reason opposes this (seepage 18 here). One plausible-soundingobjection is that IEX privileges its own router, which comes at the expense of other brokers’ routers, and that is unfair to the other brokers. Here’s Larry Tabb: From brokers perspective, their order routers are not on par with the IEX router. Since the IEX routing broker does not go over the speed bump (on outbound routes) and every other brokers router goes over the speed bump, the IEX routing broker sees an outbound order 350 microseconds before everyone else. This gives the IEX routing broker an advantage. Theproblem is that brokers don’t seem to be makingthis objection. And since IEX sells its routing services to its exchange members (i.e. brokers), not to buy-side institutions, I’m not sure how much of a competitive advantage it is. On the other hand, BATS argues: Crucially, unlike IEX, which explicitly markets to its customers the architectural advantage of sending IEX an order first and then using the IEX routing broker-dealer to reach other trading venues, no existing exchange could make the same marketing pitch because, unlike IEX, no such actual advantage exists to using the exchanges routing broker-dealers. That is true, but I think IEX would just say that that’s a feature, not a bug. IEX, unlike other exchanges, can advertise that its routing system is good for its customers because, unlike other exchanges’, it is good for its customers. But that’s good! The full example: Assume that the NBBO is $10.00 (100) x $10.01 (200). IEX is quoting at $10.00 (100) x $10.01 (100) and Exchange A is quoting at $9.99 (100) x $10.01 (100). A market order to sell is entered into IEX for 200 shares. IEX will execute the incoming order against the displayed order on its book at $10.00 for 100 shares and a message is sent out to market data recipients notifying them of the execution and corresponding NBBO update. Sequentially, IEX would give the balance of the order to its routing broker-dealer, which in turn would route the balance of the order to another trading venue. However, because the POP and its delay are applied to only the execution message and not the order sent by IEXs routing broker-dealer, the routed order will reach the other trading venue before the execution message and corresponding NBBO update. If IEX routes 100 shares to another venue for execution, and that other venue has midpoint or pegged orders, the routed order will execute based on what IEX knows to be a stale, or non-updated NBBO. For instance, if the incoming order were to interact with a midpoint order at the other venue, it would execute at $10.005 based on a stale NBBO of $10.00 x $10.01, instead of $10.00, which is the correct price. It might, insofar as IEX reports trades to the SIP (the consolidated trading feed) without the delay, so if the SIP could update faster than IEX’s router delayed by 350 microseconds then that wouldfix this problem. But you’re still relying on the SIP and NYSE updating prices before IEX’s router gets there, and the more IEX slows down its router the worse execution it is getting for its clients. A related worry, which you see sort of vaguely mentioned in the comments, is that high-frequency traders specializing in latency arbitrage would use IEX midpoint peg or routable orders to conduct that arbitrage. E.g.,here is BATS again: Thus, the IEX routing broker-dealer with its exclusive latency advantage will become a desired tool of those market participants that use latency arbitrage strategies. As a facility of an exchange, the IEX routing broker-dealer must be available to all broker-dealer members of IEX on a fair access basis, and it will be exploited by algorithms, proprietary trading firms and foreign broker dealers that will have full access to the IEX exchange and its facilities. The Commissions approval of the IEX latency advantaged routing broker-dealer will result in other exchanges adopting similar techniques to protect their own resting orders from participants that may otherwise exploit the very market that was supposed to simplify our markets and protect investors. And then, of course, it will come full circle. When all exchanges adopt the solution that IEX is proposing, the same exact issues will re-emerge that IEX is purportedly resolving. If BATS implemented a 350 microsecond delay in reporting executions but not routing orders, all routed orders from BATS to IEX would reach IEX and be executed before the quote update would reach IEX from BATS, even if IEX was utilizing BATSs direct feeds. I don’t exactly know how HFTs would take advantage of the latency edge provided by IEXorders, but people do talk about it. A related objection is that IEX’s structure favors“dark,” undisplayed, pegged orders over “lit,” displayed orders, and that lit orders are better for market efficiency and price discovery. As Citadel says: If a participant submits a non-pegged order and wants to change the price, the participant would have to cancel the original order, wait 350 microseconds until the message travels through the IEX Access Delay, and submit a new order that would also be delayed an additional 350 microseconds before it hits the trading system. The IEX structure thus favorsdarkliquidity in the form of pegged orders over displayed orders because displayed orders cannot react to market changes without incurring a 350 microsecond delay, while pegged orders, which are non-displayed on IEX, are not subject to this limitation. By promoting the use of hidden orders anddarkliquidity on a lit venue over displayed orders, IEXs contribution to the critical price discovery role that exchanges play will be significantly limited. IEXs structure suggests that IEXs real aim is to create adarkpool on a lit venue to provide itself with regulatory immunity and other benefits afforded to national securities exchanges. Here’s IEX’s response: All pegged orders offered by all exchanges and ATSs are able to reprice based on each venues systems for updating its own understanding of market prices, while non-pegged orders require action to adjust the price. Thus pegged orders can always reprice more quickly than non-pegged orders, provided that the exchange has the most up to date view of the market. IEX expects as an exchange to offer a quality market for both displayed and non-displayed orders. We think it is vitally important to continue to be able to offer quality execution to all investors through theuse of pegged order types by updating our understanding of market prices as quickly as possible. At the same time, there are other factors that will encourage many participants to send displayed orders –among others, all non- displayed orders will cede priority to displayed orders at the same price. Further, IEX plans to discount pricing to both provide and access displayed orders relative to non-displayed orders. But it’s worth considering Norges Bank’s comment letter: Intermediation through liquidity provisioning is a necessary and beneficial component of asset markets, and should be adequately rewarded. Managing quotes to optimally control inventory risk is a key part of a liquidity provider’s business model –reducing latency makes this process easier. However, this process may also lead to quote sizes which are smaller than necessary from an inventory risk control perspective, and intraday volatility that is greater than required for adequate compensation of liquidity provisioning services. We view this as a form of “rent extraction”. As economic theory tells us, that represents a deadweight loss for the market overall. And: We would therefore expect IEX quotes to be at the NBBO relatively less frequently than those of other exchanges, but possibly less fleeting and potentially with more depth. This may be a positive development­ — quotes on IEX may be more indicative of true liquidity availability than those on other exchanges, which have been described as “phantom liquidity”. Possibly, as we’ve discussed, too efficient, in the sense that a market that updates prices too efficiently will under-reward investment in fundamental research. Robert P. Bartlett III and Justin McCrary write: Why the delay? One reason may be that for the S.E.C. to make a determination, it may first have to take a stand on a form of high-frequency trading known as latency arbitrage, which is a strategy whereby traders use high-speed data feeds from exchanges to profit off investors who use slower feeds. To date, the agency has avoided taking a position on this form of trading, but IEXs application may finally force it to do so. I think that is part of it.